Blog Post

Blogs review: the discounting debate in climate change mitigation

What’s at stake: Decisions with respect to climate change action depend on various parameters, but a particularly important one is the choice of the social discount rate (SDR), which captures – among other things – the weight at which we discount the welfare of future generations. This discounting decision has direct implications as to whether it is necessary to delay or accelerate climate change mitigation policies. In discussions about the choice of the appropriate SDR, two main approaches have emerged: an a priori approach (as proposed by Stern) and a market based approach (as proposed by Nordhaus and Weitzman).

By: and Date: April 20, 2012 Topic: Energy & Climate

What’s at stake: Decisions with respect to climate change action depend on various parameters, but a particularly important one is the choice of the social discount rate (SDR), which captures – among other things – the weight at which we discount the welfare of future generations. This discounting decision has direct implications as to whether it is necessary to delay or accelerate climate change mitigation policies. In discussions about the choice of the appropriate SDR, two main approaches have emerged: an a priori approach (as proposed by Stern) and a market based approach (as proposed by Nordhaus and Weitzman).

Standard Cost-Benefit Analysis

The 2006 Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change broke down the social discount rate into three components: the pure time discount rate (d), the elasticity of the social marginal utility of consumption with respect to consumption (h), and the growth rate of technology (g): SDR = d + hg. In terms of numeric values, Stern sets d=0.001, implying a 0.1% chance of human extinction each year. Stern thus basically treats current and future generations equally; the only difference between the two arises from a small possibility of extinction. Stern then sets h=1, which implies that the elasticity of marginal consumption between better-off and worse-off individuals is equal to the ratio of their wealth. A high value of h means that transfers of wealth from rich to poor are endorsed, while a low h implies little concern about distributional equality. Stern then goes on to make a positive assumption about the growth rate of technology and sets g=1.3%. This leads to an SDR of 1.4%. With this value, urgent action against climate change is warranted. The practical policy implication Stern calls for is an investment of 1% of global GDP in the fight against CO2 emissions, which would stabilize global stocks of GHG below the 550ppm threshold.

Martin Weitzman – of Harvard University – argues in the Journal of Economic Literature that the conclusions of the report rely on parameter values that are imposed a priori rather than chosen in a democratic manner. The author argues that it is possible to come up with more reasonable numbers based on observed behavior in the marketplace. One option would be an SDR of 6%, obtained by setting d=2%, h=2, and g=2%. He further suggests that the general uncertainty surrounding the topic warrants a higher SDR. This need not be 6, as in the previous example and could also lie in the 2-4 range. This would create a middle-ground between Stern’s recommendations and more skeptical views according to which climate change action should be delayed.

William Nordhaus argues that the findings of Stern – that “if we don’t act, the overall costs and risks of climate change will be equivalent to losing at least 5% of global GDP each year, now and forever. If a wider range of risks and impacts is taken into account, the estimates of damage could rise to 20% of GDP or more” – differ markedly from economic models that calculate least-cost emissions paths to stabilize concentrations or paths that balance the costs and benefits of emissions reductions. Mainstream economic models definitely find it economically beneficial to take steps today to slow global warming, but efficient policies generally involve modest rates of emissions reductions in the near term, followed by sharp reductions in the medium and long term. Nordhaus suggests taking an h=3 and keeping d close to 0. This, he argues, would lead to real returns and savings rates closer to values observed in the economy. Stern’s findings rely on a low discount rate and low inequality aversion, which results in savings rates and real returns which are very different from actual economic values. In a recent article for the NYT Review of Books, Nordhaus argues in favor of immediate moderate action, via cap-and-trade or carbon taxes.

Partha Dasgupta – of Cambridge University – is suspicious as to whether Stern’s theory remains defensible in the face of small changes in parameter values. If a g=0 were to come about (while keeping d and h fixed at the values chosen by Stern), Dasgupta argues that current generations ought to save 97.5% of current production for future generations. He thus accuses Stern’s theory of exhibiting normative bias. Brad DeLong responds to Dasgupta’s assessment. DeLong considers the arithmetic underlying Dasgupta’s conclusion and finds that a savings rate of 22.5%, not of 97.5 %, is in fact required. This renders Stern’s prescription more reasonable. DeLong also advocates a d=0, which implies that current and future generations carry equal weight in climate change mitigation. DeLong goes on to express his agreement with Dasgupta with regards to the importance of the h parameter. He suggests that different hs, in the range of 1 to 5, should be considered and that this should have also been the approach of the Stern Review.

Richard Tol does a meta-analysis of the social cost of carbon. The author finds that there is a downward trend in the estimates of the social cost of carbon and that the Stern Review is an outlier. Its impact estimates are pessimistic even when compared to other studies in the gray literature and other estimates that use low discount rates. The uncertainty about the social cost of carbon is so large that the tails of the distribution may dominate the conclusions.

Fat tails and the economics of climate change

In a recent article, Martin Weitzmann argues that the most striking feature of the economics of climate change is that its extreme downside is nonnegligible and that the way in which this deep uncertainty is conceptualized and formalized influences the outcomes of any reasonable cost-benefit analysis (CBA) of climate change. The author does not argue that the standard model is wrong or even implausible, but rather that it may not be robust with respect to the modeling of catastrophic outcomes.

He suggests that the unprecedented scale and speed of GHG increases brings policy makers into uncharted territory, rendering climate predictions very difficult. Current CBA models assume that the climate will respond in a certain way to increased GHG emissions and that this response will follow a distribution with thin tails. This implies very little concern for potentially extreme outcomes. Weitzman points out that modeling tail probabilities one way or the other can have huge consequences. He contrasts a Pareto distribution with a normal distribution, assuming that the latter is usually at the heart of CBA models. Carrying out simulations using the two leads to extremely different estimates, particularly regarding the reactiveness of high-temperature probabilities to the level of GHGs.  He concludes that the focus should be shifted away from central tendencies and towards extreme tails.

William Nordhaus provides an assessment of Weitzman’s initial views on this topic. He particularly focuses on Weitzman’s point that under certain strict assumptions about the structure of uncertainty and preferences, “society has an indefinitely large expected loss from high-consequence, low-probability events” (the ‘dismal theory’). Nordhaus stresses that the theory is only applicable under very limited conditions involving strong risk aversion, a fat tail for the uncertain variables and an inability on society’s part to act in time against climate change. He finds nonetheless that tail events deserve attention and careful analysis and acknowledges Weitzman’s merit in drawing attention to the existence of deep uncertainties. He goes on to suggest that it is unclear when cost-benefit analysis should or should not be employed. He concludes that this decision will rest largely on the “the uncertainty surrounding specific issues and phenomena, as well as attitudes toward risk.”


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

View comments
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The debate on euro-area reform

A paper jointly written by 14 French and German economists set off a debate about the reform of euro-area macroeconomic governance. We review economists’ opinions about it.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation Date: April 16, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Latvia’s money laundering scandal

Latvia’s third largest bank ABLV sought emergency liquidity from the ECB and eventually voted to start a process of voluntary liquidation, after being accused by US authorities of large-scale money laundering and having failed to produce a survival plan. What does it mean for the ECB?

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation Date: April 9, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Milton Friedman's " The role of monetary policy" - 50 years later

In March 1968, Milton Friedman’s “The Role of Monetary Policy” - after his famous presidential address to the American Economic Association - was published in the American Economic Review. 50 years later, economists reflect on this famous work.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: April 3, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The Brexit Transition Deal

Michel Barnier, the European Union’s Brexit negotiator, and David Davis, Britain’s Brexit secretary, announced a transition deal on March 19. We review recently published opinions about the deal and its implications.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: March 26, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Central banks in the age of populism

Two years of elections have shown that we live in an age of increasing political and economic populism. What are the consequences of that for central banks? We explore opinions about it, from both 2017 and more recently.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation Date: March 19, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Are we steel friends?

The U.S. administration is considering to impose tariffs on steel (25%) and aluminium (10%), based on a national security argument. We review economists’ views about this major shift in U.S.’ trade policy.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: March 12, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Getting accustomed to Brexit - UK and the customs union scenario

The Labour Party’s support of customs union membership has the potential to change the course of Brexit, with 13 months left to close negotiations. This week we review the commentary around the possibility of a post-Brexit EU-UK Customs Union.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: March 5, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The Italian elections

Italy goes to the polls on March 4, with a new electoral law that is largely viewed as unable to deliver a stable government. We review recent opinions and expectations,  as well as economists’ assessment of the cost/coverage of parties’ economic promises. 

By: Silvia Merler Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: February 26, 2018
Read article More by this author

Blog Post

Venezuela’s hyperinflation

The International Monetary Fund forecasts Venezuelan inflation spiralling to 13,000 percent this year. As President Maduro is expected to introduce the “petro” cryptocurrency next week, we review economists’ recent (and less recent) opinions on the current crisis.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: February 19, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The stock market slide

The stock market dropped last week, leading to questions and debates as to the underlying reasons. We review economists’ views on the issue.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation Date: February 12, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Economies of States, Economies of Cities

Both in Europe and the US, economists are starting to notice how the economies of cities have been sometimes diverging from the economies of states. While some areas thrive, others may be permanently left behind. Maybe it is time to adopt a more clearly sub-national perspective. We review recent contributions on this issue.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: February 5, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Rebuilding macroeconomics: Initial reflections on a major theory project

The ‘Rebuilding Macroeconomic Theory Project’ came to an end in the most recent volume of the Oxford Review of Economic Policy; how were the various papers’ conclusions received?

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: January 29, 2018
Load more posts