Blog Post

Blogs review: Markets without a price

What’s at stake: Lloyd Shapley and Alvin Roth have won the Nobel Prize in economics “for the theory of stable allocations and the practice of market design”, which relate to the study of social allocation problems where money as a medium of exchange is ruled out or at least constrained. Roth has built on the insight of Gale and Shapley to come-up with precise conditions under which market design can achieve efficient allocations and has applied these lessons to a variety of real world matching problems such as organ exchange, college admissions and the design of the economics Job Market.

By: Date: October 19, 2012 Global Economics & Governance Tags & Topics

­What’s at stake: Lloyd Shapley and Alvin Roth have won the Nobel Prize in economics “for the theory of stable allocations and the practice of market design”, which relate to the study of social allocation problems where money as a medium of exchange is ruled out or at least constrained. Roth has built on the insight of Gale and Shapley to come-up with precise conditions under which market design can achieve efficient allocations and has applied these lessons to a variety of real world matching problems such as organ exchange, college admissions and the design of the economics Job Market.

Welfare gains in priceless allocations and the future of repugnance

Greg Ip writes that money is a handy way of denominating prices and economists love prices because they are so efficient at allocating supply and demand so as to maximize welfare. Yet markets do not have to have money or prices to serve that welfare-maximizing function. That distinction lies at the heart of the work that won this year’s Nobel Prize in economics.

Arindrajit Dube (HT Mark Thoma) writes that the concrete applications that are discussed as ways of "improving the performance of many markets" – such as matching residents to hospitals, matching donors to organs, and students to schools – are not really "markets." At least not if we think of markets as institutions where prices help clear supply and demand. Instead, they involve non-market interactions, where the matches are actually formed by centralized exchanges.

In a recent essay (HT Stephen Dubner), Al Roth argues that an important constraint for the existence of a clearing price is repugnance – the distaste for certain kinds of transactions – which acts as a real constraint, every bit as real as the constraints imposed by technology or by the requirements of incentives and efficiency. Roth points in JEP paper that repugnance borders do shift over time, although quite slowly. The author considers a range of examples from lending money for interest to bans on eating horse meat in California to bans on dwarf tossing in France.

The Gale-Shapley deferred choice algorithm and the “socialist calculation” debate

Alex Tabarrok writes that the field of matching may be said to start with the Gale-Shapley deferred choice algorithm. Here is how it works, applied to men and women and marriage. Each man proposes to his first ranked choice. Each woman rejects any unacceptable proposals but defers accepting her remaining suitors. Each rejected man proposes to his second ranked choice. Each woman now rejects again any unacceptable proposals, which may include previous suitors who have now become unacceptable. The process repeats until no further proposals are made; each woman then accepts her most preferred suitors and the matches are made.

Timothy Taylor writes that another key insight is that although the deferred-acceptance procedure is usually explained as a step-by-step process, where parties make one offer at a time, an equivalent process can be run by a clearinghouse, if the parties submit sufficient information. And this is where Alvin Roth enters the picture, bringing in detailed practical implications for analysis. As one might expect, these real-world cases raise various practical problems. Are there ways of gaming the system by not listing your first choice, which you are perhaps unlikely to get anyway, and pretending great enthusiasm for your fifth choice, which you are more likely to get? Such outcomes are sometimes possible in practical settings, but it proves much harder to game these mechanisms than one might think. Usually, you’re better off just giving your true preferences and seeing how the mechanism plays itself out.

 

Source: Super Freakonomics Illustrated

To implement the Gale-Shapley algorithm for the marriage market yourself, you can visit UC Berkeley’s Mathsite.

Arindrajit Dube writes that mathematically speaking, the Gale-Shapley algorithm is part of a class of optimal matching algorithms, which is equivalent to the Monge-Kantorovich optimal transport solution, a signature accomplishment of Soviet mathematics. A popular view today is that it is not possible to implement an efficient allocation using planning because people don’t have the incentives to reveal their true preferences to begin with, which makes this whole exercise rather pointless. A variant of this position was originally articulated by Austrian economists, including Ludwig von Mises, during the so called "socialist calculation" debate of the early 20th century. And in many cases this criticism rings true. However, it does not follow that the truthful revelation problem is ubiquitous. For example, it is interesting to note that Alvin Roth and Elliott Peranson show that when implementing optimal matching, this problem may be smaller than one might imagine: when each applicant only interviews a small number of positions overall, the gains from strategic manipulation of preferences are small. This, too, has important implications for the "socialist calculation" debate, as it suggests that for a range of cases, a centralized exchange implementing planning without using prices can (and indeed does) implement relatively efficient allocations.

Joshua Gans writes that Roth has set down a set of principles for market designers. Basically, market design works when you can find rules that encourage thickness (lots of buyers and sellers), avoid congestion and are safe (that people think transactions will actually take place on the terms agreed). Put those things together and you are a good way to having yourself a well-functioning market.

The design of the Economics Job Market… and that of the NFL

Al Roth is also the chair of the AEA’s Ad Hoc Committee on the Job Market. The first of the Committee’s recommendations to be put in practice was the Economics Job Scamble, a web page on which applicants and employers could indicate their continued availability as of late March. The second, which went online November 20, 2006, is that the AEA will facilitate Signaling for Interviews in the Economics Job Market, to allow applicants to send up to two signals to employers with whom they would like to interview. In a email to Greg Mankiw, Al Roth explains that just as the idea of the scramble was to add some thickness to the late (March-April) part of the market, the idea of signaling is to reduce some of the congestion in the thick, January interviews part of the market.

Real Time Economics write that now that Roth and Shapley have won the Nobel, the NFL will finally listen to what they have to say. In 2010 article, three Harvard University researchers who studied market design under Roth argues that the National Football League has one of the worst systems in all of industry for matching talented workers with the right employers. They then helped create a new system for the NFL’s draft. But the NFL did NOT take the Nobel-worthy advice.

The Shapley value

Joshua Gans writes at Digitopoly that Lloyd Shapley is best known in economics for the Shapley value, which is a way of thinking about who might capture value in a multi-lateral negotiation. Henrik Jensen writes that the concept was applied to political decision making together with Martin Shubik in 1954, as the Shapley-Shubik index. It is a simple index that measures the voting power of parties, and, in particular, shows that number of seats in a committee or parliament is not the same as power. It is the power of the coalitions in which a party can be decisive, i.e., pivotal, that matters.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

Comments

Read article More on this topic

Blog Post

Uuriintuya Batsaikhan
Pia Hüttl

The benefits and drawbacks of TTIP

What’s at stake: Since the recent leak of documents on TTIP (Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership) negotiations, there has been renewed interest in the trade deal. This blog review looks at studies on the estimated impacts of TTIP on growth, labour markets and social conditions. We also summarise its impact on countries outside the deal, and look at the debates surrounding its counterpart, the TPP (Trans-Pacific Partnership).

By: Uuriintuya Batsaikhan and Pia Hüttl Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: May 23, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

Regulation and growth

What’s at stake: A heated debate took place this week on the blogosphere on the link between regulation and growth following an op-ed by John Cochrane claiming the US economy could be five times richer if regulations were scrapped.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: May 16, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

The economics of crime and punishment

What’s at stake: The Senate announced this week revisions to a sentencing reform bill – the Sentencing Reform and Corrections Act – that would lower mandatory minimums for some low-level drug crimes.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: May 2, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

Understanding HM Treasury’s Brexit analysis

What’s at stake: The UK will hold a referendum on its membership of the EU on June 23rd 2016. Her Majesty’s Treasury released an assessment of the impact of Brexit finding that the economy would be between 3 and 7% smaller in 2030 if the UK left the EU than it would be if it stayed in.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: April 25, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

Trade deficits and jobs at the ZLB

What’s at stake: In the populist narrative against globalization, trade deficits are seen as costing jobs. While this mercantilist view of the world is hard to square in normal times, a number of authors have suggested that the intellectual basis for that view is stronger in a liquidity trap.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: April 4, 2016
Read article More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

The procyclicality of TFP growth

What’s at stake: The argument that total factor productivity (TFP) is procyclical has been getting a lot of airtime over the past few weeks as it was central to understanding the recent controversy over the economic impact of Sanders. But it also speaks to the question of the current TFP slowdown and to the issue of a clean separation between cycles and trends.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance, Global Economics & Governance Date: March 29, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

The trade-backlash explanation of Trump & Sanders

What’s at stake: The success of presidential candidates Donald Trump and Bernie Sanders has had bloggers wondered whether the backlash against globalization is eventually getting political traction.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: March 21, 2016
Read article More on this topic

Blog Post

Pia Hüttl
Alvaro Leandro

Helicopter drops reloaded

What’s at stake: Central banks have recently been scaling up their unconventional monetary policy measures. Discussions about helicopter money seem to be getting ever louder. We review the theoretical discussions, the effectiveness of tax-rebates and legal and political complications

By: Pia Hüttl and Alvaro Leandro Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: March 14, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

The elimination of high denomination notes

What’s at stake: As high-denomination notes (HDNs) make it easier to transact crime, finance terrorism, and evade taxes, a number of commentators have called for their elimination.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: March 7, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

The Sanders controversy

What’s at stake: A recent study claiming that Sanders policies would produce 5.3 percent growth a year over the next decade has been at the center of this week’s discussions in the blogosphere.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: February 29, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

The impotency of central banks

What’s at stake: The negative market reaction to the latest efforts to provide further monetary stimulus has generated an important discussion on whether central banks have lost credibility in their abilities to fight downside risks and shore up economies.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: February 22, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Jérémie Cohen-Setton

Blaming the Fed for the Great Recession

What’s at stake: Following an article in the New York Times by David Beckworth and Ramesh Ponnuru, the conversation on the blogosphere was dominated this week by the question of whether the Fed actually caused the Great Recession. While not mainstream, this narrative recently received a boost as Ted Cruz, a Republican candidate for the White House, championed it.

By: Jérémie Cohen-Setton Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: February 1, 2016
Load more posts