Blog Post

Blogs review: Empirical and theoretical multiplier uncertainty

What’s at stake: A recent “box” in the first chapter of the WEO, co-authored by IMF Chief Economist Olivier Blanchard and his colleague Daniel Leigh, have reinvigorated the debate over whether austerity measures imposed on struggling eurozone countries has contributed to a deepening recession. On Wednesday, the European Commission responded with its own “box” pointing to the importance of distinguishing permanent from temporary fiscal adjustments. Contrary to what the battle of the boxes suggests, if there is multiplier uncertainty, it is very unlikely to come from the empirical front. Rather, it may come from recent challenges to previously accepted theoretical results.

By: Date: November 12, 2012 European Macroeconomics & Governance Tags & Topics

What’s at stake: A recent “box” in the first chapter of the WEO, co-authored by IMF Chief Economist Olivier Blanchard and his colleague Daniel Leigh, have reinvigorated the debate over whether austerity measures imposed on struggling eurozone countries has contributed to a deepening recession. On Wednesday, the European Commission responded with its own “box” pointing to the importance of distinguishing permanent from temporary fiscal adjustments. Contrary to what the battle of the boxes suggests, if there is multiplier uncertainty, it is very unlikely to come from the empirical front. Rather, it may come from recent challenges to previously accepted theoretical results.

The battle of the boxes

Dominic Wilson, Julian Richers and Jari Stehn have the most comprehensive discussion of the IMF box. Blanchard and Leigh show that the forecast errors from their April 2010 GDP growth forecasts for 2010 and 2011 are systematically related to their forecasts of planned fiscal consolidation. The authors argue that the overall direction of their conclusions is sensible, based on what we know of the empirical literature. But the strength of these particular relationships between GDP forecast errors and planned fiscal consolidations is sensitive to choices over time periods and the inclusion of other controls – like the 2009 structural government balance for instance.

The European Commission’s box (on page 41) argues if multipliers were underestimated, the underestimation concerned the multipliers of temporary expansions in 2010, not permanent consolidation in 2011. The 2010 stimulus measures are associated with large positive forecast errors for the countries that have implemented them. But as the impact multiplier associated with temporary fiscal contractions/expansions is substantially larger than the multiplier of permanent fiscal consolidations, bundling together countries that SR stimulus measures in 2010 with those that have undertaken measures to permanently reduce debt levels biases the estimate of the permanent consolidation multiplier in an upward direction.

How did policymakers end-up using such low multipliers?

The European Commission’s box reports the size of the multipliers used in its models. The multipliers of the Commission’s structural macroeconomic model QUEST for temporary fiscal shocks are between 0.1-0.4 for tax changes, but in the range of 0.7-1.5 for spending changes when credit constraints are high and interest rates are at the zero-lower bound. However, it is generally accepted that the impact multiplier associated with permanent fiscal consolidations is substantially smaller because of more positive crowding in effects. The QUEST has that the multiplier for such a consolidation is on average for a balanced-composition consolidation around 0.4. To account for the specificities of the current environment – ZLB, global fiscal retrenchment – the average multiplier can rise to 0.5-0.7.

Antonio Fatas writes that about eleven years ago there was a series of academic papers that estimated fiscal policy multipliers. The conclusion of the earlier papers is that multipliers were somewhere in the range 1-1.5. The academic literature on this issue grew very fast with a large number of papers confirming the earlier estimates but also with a set of other papers that challenge the size of fiscal multipliers. In particular, papers that used events such as wars tended to find smaller multipliers. As soon as the 2008 crisis started the debate went from a simple academic discussion to an urgent policy issue. Since then the debate has become much more ideological than academic. We have had a series of additional academic papers that, if any, suggest that multipliers are even larger than the initial estimates because of the special circumstances we are in. But these new (and old) academic results have simply be displaced by the ideological debate that followed the fiscal policy stimulus of the 2008-2009 period.

Paul Krugman writes that policy makers basically threw out everything we’ve learned about business cycles these past 80 years in favor of doctrines that made them feel comfortable. But to which extent should academics be rude to policymakers? This is basically an operational question; as Mark Thoma says, the goal is to change minds — although the big question there is whether you’re trying to change the minds of the policy makers themselves, or the minds of other people, so we can get a new and better set of policy makers. It wasn’t nice to characterize the doctrine of expansionary austerity as belief in the confidence fairy (or to make fun of policymakers that are “shocked shocked” to find out what we already knew), but I do believe that it focused the discussion in a way that a less caustic approach would not have achieved.

Are large fiscal multipliers at the ZLB an artifact of log-linearization?

Interestingly, the biggest challenge to large multipliers does not seem to come from the empirical front, but rather from the theoretical front.

Mark Thoma writes that one thing that doesn’t get enough attention in DSGE models is the constraints, implicit assumptions, etc. imposed when the theoretical model is log-linearized. The paper below helps fill this gap by comparing a theoretical true economy to its log-linearized counterpart, and showing that the results of the two models can be quite different when the economy is at the zero bound.

Anton Braun, Lena Mareen Korber and Yuichiro Waki (HT Mark Thoma) write that using the log-linearized equilibrium conditions gives incorrect results about existence and uniqueness of equilibrium and provides an incorrect classification of the types of zero-bound equilibria that can arise in the true economy. These problems are severe. For instance, while the government purchase multiplier is above two in the log-linearized economy it is about one in the true economy. The authors make these points using a stochastic NK model that is similar to specifications considered in Eggertsson (2011) and Woodford (2011).

Lawrence J. Christiano and Martin Eichenbaum write that working with the actual nonlinear equilibrium conditions, they find the existence of equilibriums that are not visible to analyses based on linearization, as well as sunspot equilibriums. These findings challenge the findings about the properties of the ZLB so far reported. The authors find, however, that the equilibriums that are invisible to analyses using linearization are not E-learnable and so those equilibriums may perhaps be treated as mathematical curiosities. In addition, evidence that the quality of linear approximations is poor rests on examples where output deviates by more than 20 percent from its steady state, cases where no one would expect linear approximations to work well. For perturbations of reasonable size, the conclusions arrived at in the zlb analysis that use linear approximations appear to be robust.

Are fiscal multipliers smaller in a currency union?

Emmanuel Fahri and Ivan Werming (HT Simon Wren-Lewis and Marginal Revolution) have what may become the ultimate paper on fiscal policy at the ZLB and in a Monetary Union. Simon Wren-Lewis notes that the authors focus on the ‘consumption multiplier’, which is the impact of government spending on consumption. So in a closed economy a consumption multiplier of zero is a government spending multiplier of one (there is no capital).

Emmanuel Fahri and Ivan Werming find the surprising result that fiscal multipliers are necessarily lower whenever the exchange rate is fixed. The crucial difference is in monetary policy: although a fixed exchange rate implies a fixed nominal interest rate, the converse is not true. Indeed, the authors prove that the liquidity trap analysis implicitly combines a shock to government spending with a one-off devaluation. The positive response of consumption relies entirely on this devaluation. A currency union rules out such devaluations, explaining the negative response of consumption. The authors also explore non-Ricardian effects from fiscal policy by introducing hand-to- mouth consumers – a tractable way of modeling liquidity constraints. In a liquidity trap as well as in a currency union, government spending now has an additional stimulative effect as it increases the income and consumption of hand-to-mouth agents. But although there is an additional effect, the comparison of fiscal multipliers in a liquidity trap and a currency union, are unaffected.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

View comments
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

Big data and first-degree price discrimination

What’s at stake: first-degree price discrimination - or person-specific pricing, had until recently been considered a theoretical case with unlikely real-world application. Yet the increasing availability of big data could make this possible. We review recent contributions on this issue.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Innovation & Competition Policy Date: February 20, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Pia Hüttl

Inflation's comeback

What at stake: After years of deflationary pressures and anaemic economic performance, inflation seems to be on the rise again, both in the US and the euro area. Does this comeback mark a return to target? Will it be sustained, and what should central banks be thinking? These are among the questions raised in the blogosphere.

By: Pia Hüttl Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: February 13, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

Is Germany a currency manipulator?

What’s at stake: the Financial Times reports that Peter Navarro, head of the US’s National Trade Council, has accused Germany of currency manipulation. He claims that the country uses a 'grossly undervalued' Euro to 'exploit' its trading partners. Angela Merkel replied that the Euro is managed by the European Central Bank, on which Germany does not exert influence. We review what the economic blogosphere thinks of this.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: February 6, 2017
Read article More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

Climate change and financial markets

What’s at stake: Ever since the 2016 Paris Agreement to reduce emissions was signed, researchers have been looking at the impact that moves towards a low-carbon economy might have on financial markets and financial stability. We review these contributions here. 

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Energy & Climate, Finance & Financial Regulation Date: January 30, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

Tariffs and the American poor

What’s at stake: much has been said and debated — during the US election and beyond — about the distributional impact of free trade on the disadvantaged. But what would be the distributional impact of a new protectionism instead?

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: January 23, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

The economic effects of migration

What’s at stake: migration is currently a very hot topic in both the US and the EU. Immigration issues have come to the forefront due to the problem of rapidly ageing populations, the refugee crisis, and growing anti-immigration political rhetoric. But what do we know about the economic effects of migration?

By: Silvia Merler Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: January 16, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

Compensating the “losers” of globalisation

What’s at stake: According to some, 2016’s political turmoil shows that the so-called “losers” of globalisation are striking back. There is, however, little agreement on how government should respond to this challenge.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: January 9, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

2016: The end

What’s at stake: 2016 is coming to an end. It will be remembered as an annus mirabilis and horribilis, at the same time. 2016 brought us some previously unthinkable political shocks, and admittedly took away some of our finest musicians. It also couldn’t help taking away Willy Wonka and Princess Leia, making this a much sadder Galaxy. This raises an obvious question: what are we in for, in 2017?

By: Silvia Merler Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: December 31, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

The American dream

What’s at stake: historian James Truslow Adams, in his 1931 book The Epic of America, stated that the American dream is "that dream of a land in which life should be better and richer and fuller for everyone, with opportunity for each according to ability or achievement”. Few ideas have ever been as powerful as the “American Dream”, and many recent political events hinge on the fear that this “dream” may be dead. Meanwhile, researchers have been trying to measure the reality behind the dream.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: December 19, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

The political economy of macroprudential policy

What’s at stake: the emergence of renewed interest in macroprudential policy has characterised the aftermath of the great recession. There is not yet full agreement on what the tasks of macroprudential policy is or how it should be carried out, but there is a clear understanding that there is an important political economy dimension to it. We review some of the recent contribution on this.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: December 12, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Pia Hüttl

Macroeconomics in the crossfire (again)

What’s at stake: After a first go at macroeconomics and its flaws a year ago, Paul Romer kicked off the debate again with a recent essay on how macroeconomics has gone backwards. The way that this debate, along with the debate of the role of economics in general, feeds into today's election woes, has also attracted attention in the blogosphere.

By: Pia Hüttl Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: December 5, 2016
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

The Italian referendum

What’s at stake: on 4 December, Italy will hold a referendum on a proposed constitutional reform approved by Parliament in April. The reform, which was designed in tandem with a new electoral law, aims to overcome Italy’s “perfect bicameralism” by changing the structure and role of the Italian Senate. It also changes the distribution of competences between the state and regions. After the shocks of Brexit and the US election, polls are now drifting towards a defeat of the government’s position in Italy.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: November 28, 2016
Load more posts