Blog Post

Oil prices and inflation expectations

The price of crude oil has fallen even further in recent weeks, as have financial market measures of inflation expectations in the euro area, the US and the UK. We show that low oil prices drag down inflation expectations up to 5-6 years ahead, which is puzzlingly long and suggests that financial market based inflation expectations should be assessed cautiously.

By: and Date: January 21, 2016 Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance

The link between oil prices and inflation expectations has been established by a number of studies. Alejandro Badel and Joseph McGillicuddy from the Federal reserve Bank of St Luis and Nathan Sussman and Osnat Zohar from the Bank of Israel use an econometric technique to disentangle aggregate demand shocks, oil supply shocks and other oil-specific shocks.

They found that market-based measures of inflation expectations have correlated quite well with oil-related shocks since the onset of the global financial crisis, while the correlation was weaker before.

There is indeed a correlation, as shown in Figure 1. This is especially the case when considering short-maturity (for example 1 year) inflation expectations. 10-year maturity inflation expectations also appear to correlate with the oil price, but to a lesser degree.

Figure 1: Oil price and financial market-based inflation expectations (inflation swaps), weekly data, July 2007 – January 2016

Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream. Note: Market based inflation expectations refer to zero-coupon swaps over a time horizon of 1 and 10 years. Weekly average data; for the most recent week the average of 18-20 January 2016 is used.

chart_1_weekly_all

Oil-related products account for about 10 percent of consumption, and so it is straightforward that they have an impact on short-term inflation expectations. They also have an indirect impact on core inflation (see article).

However the impact on longer term expectations is more puzzling. David Elliott et al from the Bank of England show that even the expected 5-year inflation 5 years from now (5y5y inflation expectation) is influenced by current oil price movements, at least in the euro area and the United States.

Elliott and his co-authors carry out a simple regression for the daily changes in inflation swap rates on constant, contemporaneous and lagged daily percentage changes in spot oil prices, and lagged inflation swap rates (see annex). They studied the impact of oil prices on 3-year and 5y5y expectations. We use their regression model for weekly data to look at:

  • the impact of oil prices on expected average inflation for up to 10 years, and
  • the duration during which current oil price changes impact expected annual inflation in later years.

A 10 percent increase in oil prices lifts 1-year inflation expectations by 25 basis points and lifts 10-year inflation expectations (expected average inflation in the next 10 years) by about 10 basis points in the United States, as shown in Figure 2.

That is, if oil prices permanently increased by 10 percent (e.g. from 30 dollars/barrel to 33 dollars/barrel), then 1-year inflation expectations would increase by 0.25 percentage points from 0.78 percent to 1.03 percent and the 10-year inflation expectation figure would increase by 0.10 percentage points from 1.62 per cent to 1.72 per cent.

The estimated impact is slightly smaller in the UK than in the US for shorter-term expectations, but practically the same for longer-term expectations. The impact is smaller in the euro area than in the US and UK for all durations, but is still sizeable.

The recent oil price fall is the major determinant of the fall in inflation expectations. For example, the 5-year inflation swap rate for the euro area fell from 1.05 percent in late November 2015 to 0.69 percent on 20 January 2016: according to our regression result, this fall was entirely the result of falling oil prices. With unchanged oil prices from late November, the 5-year inflation swap would have marginally increased from 1.05 in late November to 1.06 on 20 January 2016 according to our regression result.

Now we turn to our second analysis: finding out how long current oil price changes impact expected annual inflation in later years. We note that the 10-year inflation expectation figure can be seen as the average of annual inflation expectations in the next 10 years, that is, the average of the current 1-year inflation expectation (e.g. from January 2016 to January 2017), the annual inflation expected between 1 year and 2 years from now (e.g. from January 2017 to January 2018), the annual inflation expected between 2 years and 3 years from now (e.g. from January 2018 to January 2019), and so on, until the annual inflation expected between 9 years and 10 years from now (e.g. from January 2025 to January 2026).

Using different maturity inflation expectations, we calculate these expected future annual inflation rates. For example, using 1-year and 2-year inflation expectations we calculate expected annual inflation one year from now. After calculating these implied annual inflation rates in future years, we use the model to assess the impact of oil prices on these expected future annual inflation rates.

Figure 3 shows rather persistent effects: we find that current changes in oil prices significantly influence annual inflation expectations up to five years in the euro area and up to six years in the US and UK.

It is puzzling that the oil price has such a persistent effect on expected future inflation. Elliott and his co-authors discuss some factors that may explain this phenomenon beyond changes in inflation expectations, such as changes in the risk premia that investors demand when trading with inflation swaps, changes in investor behaviour and market structure.

Yet it is difficult to envision a mechanism which systematically moves in parallel with the changes in oil prices. For example, it is not very likely that risk premia concerning inflation 5-6 years ahead always fall when current oil price falls, while this risk premia increases when current oil price increases. It may be possible too that a low oil price now increases the likelihood that oil price and inflation will increase in the future, in which case a current low oil price may be associated with a higher risk premia about future inflation.

Another explanation for this puzzle may be that there is a common factor behind current oil price and expected future inflation changes, as Elliott and his co-authors argue. For example weak expected future demand may drive down oil prices now, and simultaneously expectations about future inflation.

In any case, we can draw two key conclusions.

First, since falling oil prices are strongly associated with falling inflation expectations, falling market-based inflation expectations (even at long maturities) cannot be taken as evidence against the effectiveness of the ECB’s quantitate easing.

This is because oil price changes are rather exogenous to ECB’s quantitate easing (we say “rather” and not “fully”, because if QE is able to revive the euro area economy, then it also increases European demand for oil, which may increase oil prices, yet we believe this channel is rather weak compared to the other factors influencing oil prices and even a more aggressive monetary policy would have not been able to prevent the recent falls in oil prices). Therefore, this conclusion is analogous to the conclusion we draw in a blog post last week analysing the impact of oil prices on core inflation.

Second, financial market-based inflation expectations should be assessed cautiously, because they are very sensitive to oil prices even for puzzlingly longer maturities, and can also be influenced by various other factors.

Annex: the regression

David Elliott, Chris Jackson, Marek Raczko and Matt Roberts-Sklar present a simple regression model for the daily changes in inflation swap rates on constant, contemporaneous and lagged daily percentage changes in spot oil prices, and lagged inflation swap rates.

We use the very same model, but we use weekly data for two reasons. First, euro-area data is rather noisy and the use of weekly average data reduces the noise. Second, for daily data we found that additional lags of changes in oil prices are also significant for all three economies and therefore amendments to the model would be justified. But for weekly data we found that the contemporaneous and one lag for the oil price change is sufficient.

Therefore, the regression model we estimate is the following:

ZD_PH_21_1_16_1,

where  ZD_PH_21_1_16_2 is a market-based measure of inflation expectations (annualised rate in percent),ZD_PH_21_1_16_3  is the difference operator, i.e. ZD_PH_21_1_16_4 , ZD_PH_21_1_16_5 is the weekly percent change in the price of oil measured in local currency, ZD_PH_21_1_16_6 is the error term and ZD_PH_21_1_16_7 are parameters to be estimated.

We also looked at whether expectations about future oil prices influence inflation expectations, by using forward rates for Brent oil price (and in the case of the euro area and UK, forward rates for exchange rate against the US dollar to calculate the Brent forward rate in domestic currency). However, the expected change in oil price never worked in our regressions: the estimated parameters were either statistically non-significant, or they were negative, counter-intuitively implying that an expected increase in oil prices leads to a decline in expected inflation.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

View comments
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Podcast

Podcast

Backstage: Japan’s inflation problem and monetary policy options

Bruegel senior fellow Zsolt Darvas welcomes Sayuri Shirai, professor at Keio University, visiting scholar at the Asian Development Bank Institute and former Member of the Policy Board of the Bank of Japan (BOJ), for a discussion of the Japanese monetary policy outlook. 

By: The Sound of Economics Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: October 26, 2018
Read article Download PDF More on this topic More by this author

External Publication

The impact of global decarbonisation policies and technological improvements on oil and gas producing countries in the Middle East and North Africa

Simone Tagliapietra contributed to the IEMED Mediterranean Yearbook 2018 with a chapter on the impact of decarbonisation policies on oil and gas producing countries in the MENA region.

By: Simone Tagliapietra Topic: Energy & Climate Date: October 3, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Big Macs in big countries: an update on euro area adjustment

Have prices moved in the direction of correcting real exchange rate misalignments everywhere in the euro area in recent years? Not between the largest euro-area economies, i.e. France, Germany and Italy, says evidence from the Big Mac index. However, latest trends may be working in the right direction in these countries too.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: September 20, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The effects of Brexit on UK growth and inflation

The full consequences of Britain’s vote to leave the European Union were never going to be immediately perceptible. As we approach the second anniversary of the UK’s Brexit referendum, we can compare the subsequent economic data for the UK and the euro area and see how it diverges from the trends established before the vote.

By: Francesco Papadia Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: May 23, 2018
Read article More by this author

Blog Post

Venezuela’s hyperinflation

The International Monetary Fund forecasts Venezuelan inflation spiralling to 13,000 percent this year. As President Maduro is expected to introduce the “petro” cryptocurrency next week, we review economists’ recent (and less recent) opinions on the current crisis.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: February 19, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The exchange rate and inflation in the euro-area: words following facts

The reduced references in the speeches of the President and Vice-president of the ECB to exchange rate changes in assessing inflation developments correspond to a decreased pass-through from the exchange rate to inflation. So, as it should be, words have followed facts

By: Francesco Papadia Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: February 16, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The stock market slide

The stock market dropped last week, leading to questions and debates as to the underlying reasons. We review economists’ views on the issue.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation Date: February 12, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Macroprudential policy: The Maginot line of financial stability

The ability of macroprudential policies to assure financial stability and thus leave central banks free to assign the interest rate tool exclusively to price stability is unproven. As the Maginot line did not protect France from a German invasion in WWII, so macroprudential policy may not be sufficient to counter financial instability. Central banks should prepare to deal with dilemmas in the use of the interest rate.

By: Francesco Papadia Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: January 17, 2018
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Moroccan job market issues, and labour trends in the Middle East and North Africa

Morocco is an interesting case of structural labour market disequilibrium despite respectable growth, and illustrates the issues facing the region’s oil-importer countries.

By: Uri Dadush Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: December 7, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

German wages, the Phillips curve and migration in the euro area

This post studies why wages in Germany have not borne strong increases despite a relatively strong labour market. I list four reasons why announcing the death of the Phillips curve – the negative relationship between unemployment and wage growth – is premature in Germany. One of the reasons I report is substantial immigration from the rest of the EU.

By: Guntram B. Wolff Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: November 29, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Has the Phillips curve disappeared?

The Phillips curve prescribes a negative trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Economists have been recently debating on whether the curve has disappeared in the US and Europe. We report some of the most recent views.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: November 21, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

A slightly tighter ECB

The ECB’s recent decision on QE was somewhat on the dovish side. Francesco Papadia gives his view on why it is time to start a discussion about reducing the degree of ease of monetary policy.

By: Francesco Papadia Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: November 15, 2017
Load more posts