Blog Post

The Continental Partnership proposal: a reply to five main criticisms

The proposal for a Continental Partnership (CP) has received a great deal of attention. Two of the authors, André Sapir and Guntram Wolff, clarify some misunderstandings and respond to five key criticisms. They argue that the CP does not offer a way for EU members to restrict freedom of movement, nor is there a great risk of “political contagion”. Indeed, a CP arrangement could be the best route for the remaining EU members to maintain strong economic and security cooperation with the UK, while defending themselves against dumping and vetoes.

By: and Date: September 27, 2016 Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance

As Europe comes to terms with the UK electorate’s decision to leave the EU, there is great debate about the future of EU-UK relations. In this context, together with three colleagues, we recently proposed the creation of a Continental Partnership (CP) to structure the relationship between the UK and the EU after Brexit. The CP offers a relationship considerably less deep than EU membership but much closer than a free-trade agreement (FTA). So far, a FTA has been considered the default option for post-Brexit relations, even though it would also require considerable negotiation. We argued that deep economic integration between the EU and the UK could continue even without the full freedom of movement of workers, as long as a single set of rules and laws was respected and enforced in the other three dimensions of the EU single market (the free movement of goods, services and capital). We also proposed that the UK should be given a consultative role in single-market policymaking, although the EU would keep ultimate authority over the law-making process.

The CP would therefore consist of two groups of countries. On the one side are the EU member states, which share supranational institutions and participate fully in all EU policies, including the single market’s four freedoms. On the other side are those outside the EU, like the UK and possibly other European countries such as Norway, Switzerland, Turkey or Ukraine, which would not join supranational institutions and would not participate in all EU policies, especially the freedom of movement for workers. The CP would be governed by a new inter-governmental system. Its aim would be to seek not only deep economic integration (with limited labour mobility) between all the participating countries, but also potentially close cooperation in matters of foreign policy, security and defence.

Our proposal should be viewed as dealing not just with the EU-UK relationship, but with the organisation of Europe over a longer time horizon.

Thus, although motivated by Brexit in the short term, our proposal should be viewed as dealing not just with the EU-UK relationship, but with the organisation of Europe over a longer time horizon. In the next 15-20 years, the balance of economic and geopolitical power in the world will alter significantly in favour of countries outside Europe. If our part of the world is to keep a seat at the new top table, it will have to find ways to create a partnership between the EU and non-EU states.

Our proposal for a two-tier or two-circle Europe – with the EU as the inner circle and the other European countries as the outer one – has generated a lot of interest throughout Europe. Reactions have generally been either strongly positive or strongly negative.  Among our defenders, some saw a possibility to transform the inner circle, the EU, into a closer grouping of countries sharing a political project. Meanwhile, others saw the possibility to dissociate economic integration, to which they generally subscribe, from political integration, which they reject. Many also saw our proposal as useful for dealing with countries like Turkey and Ukraine, which do not belong to the EU but are seeking deeper economic ties with it. There is widespread recognition that EU enlargement has largely run its course and that another approach will be needed to deal with the EU’s neighbours.

We believe that the EU and the UK share common interests, in particular in the longer term. The two sides need to define a common vision at the start of a negotiation.

There was, however, much less consensus when it comes to the idea of applying this looser organisation of Europe to the relationship between the EU and the UK. On the EU side there are basically two objections to our proposal as far as applying it to the UK is concerned. One is mainly tactical: the timing of our proposal is considered to be wrong. By offering the UK access to the single market on terms that reflect some of the red lines of those who voted for Brexit, it is argued that we weaken the hand of the EU side at the start of a difficult negotiation. We will not discuss this issue in this blog post. Suffice it to say that our intention was not tactical but strategic: we believe that the EU and the UK share common interests, in particular in the longer term. The two sides need to define a common vision at the start of a negotiation which risks being not only difficult but also acrimonious if there is no such shared perspective.

The other, more fundamental objection concerns the substance of our proposal. Commentators on the EU side worried that its two core principles could be perilous for the functioning of the EU. These are:

  1. allowing countries in the outer circle not to participate in the freedom of movement of workers while enjoying the other three single market freedoms
  2. giving non-EU members a voice, though not a final say, in single-market policymaking

The four freedoms are at the core of the EU political project and are not negotiable for countries wanting to be part of the EU.

Before we respond to five main arguments against our proposal, we will first make one overarching clarification. We are not suggesting that EU members could be given the possibility to opt out of freedom of movement for workers – one of the four single market freedoms. This is a misunderstanding of our proposal, in which all the countries belonging to the EU would continue to be bound by the entire acquis. Thus they would still have to abide by all four freedoms without any restrictions, including the free mobility of workers. The four freedoms are at the core of the EU political project and are not negotiable for countries wanting to be part of the EU. In addition, the free movement of workers is economically indispensable for countries in the euro area, where the exchange rate is no longer available as an adjustment mechanism.

Besides this misunderstanding, there are five main criticisms which have been directed towards our proposal from the EU perspective. (This blog does not deal with reactions on the UK side.)

1. Does a soft Brexit risk political contagion?

Some commentators have feared that our proposal would lead to “political contagion”, with some EU countries demanding the same treatment as those in the outer circle. For example, Guy Verhofstadt, the leader of the ALDE group in the European Parliament (EP) who was recently appointed as EP negotiator on Brexit, has said that the UK cannot get a deal on free movement  because other EU countries may follow. (Please note this was not said in reaction to our proposal.) Likewise, the official position of the European Commission, endorsed by EU heads of state or government in Bratislava last week (without the UK), is also that the four freedoms are inseparable. So, since the UK seems unwilling to accept completely unrestricted labour mobility, the “political contagion” argument is de facto driving the UK to a hard Brexit.

We disagree with this “political contagion” view about a compromise on freedom of movement. It seems to ignore the fact that limits on the free movement of workers would only be an option for countries that are outside the EU, as explained above. Thus our proposal does not offer a way for the UK to first negotiate with its EU partners the right to limit the free circulation of workers and then to decide to remain a member of the EU. This is a legitimate concern on the EU side, but it would not be possible within the Continental Partnership framework.

There is no question in our mind that the UK would only be able to give up on the complete adherence to the four freedoms by losing its status as an EU member. This would mean losing the right to vote on EU laws but having to obey them, and also an obligation to continue paying into the EU budget. This situation of having to leave the EU to be able to limit labour mobility does not strike us as particularly attractive for most current EU members.

We believe that few, if any, EU countries would want to follow the UK’s lead.

The crucial point is the difference between belonging to the inner circle of the CP (the EU)  and being in the outer circle of the CP (outside the EU). This is not just about whether countries have to abide by all four freedoms or can introduce limits on the free circulation of labour. The countries in the outer circle also have fewer rights than those inside the EU since they cannot vote on EU legislation which applies to all CP countries. We believe that few, if any, EU countries would want to follow the UK’s lead and lose their member of the European Commission, where EU legislation originates, and their seats at the Council and the European Parliament, where EU legislation is adopted, simply because they would want to limit labour mobility with other EU countries. Therefore, in our view the risk of “political contagion” is small.

Consider the 27 current EU members besides the UK. Nineteen already belong to the euro area, which is a clear sign of their commitment to the EU as a political project. Among the remaining eight countries, all but one (Denmark) are committed to joining the euro when they can and the vast majority seem to be committed to the EU as a political project.  It is therefore difficult to see how they would benefit from a status where they have less access to EU labour markets and no decision-making power. Nonetheless, there may be a few non-euro area countries which, like the UK, are only interested in economic integration and in fact reject the EU as a political project and the free movement of workers. Perhaps these countries joined the EU only because there was no alternative way to participate in the EU single market at the time. If an alternative like the CP were to exist, these countries may prefer to leave the EU and join its outer circle. However, in our view this would not amount to “political contagion” but instead to “political clarification”.

We do not see the negotiation with the UK as a substitute for reforming the EU to make it more attractive and resilient.

More profoundly, we disagree with the view that pushing for a deal that is very disadvantageous for the UK will be a way to guarantee political consensus for political integration in the remainder of the EU. On the contrary, a political union needs to be based on the free choice of its member nations to stay. It needs shared political goals and clear benefits from membership. To put it another way, we do not see the negotiation with the UK as a substitute for reforming the EU to make it more attractive and resilient.

2. Would the UK gain at some EU members’ expense?

Many workers from Central and Eastern Europe have moved to other EU countries, including the UK, to take up employment. For these countries, the deal we propose may entail a cost. They might understandably consider it a bad deal to continue granting the UK free access to their markets for goods, services and capital while their citizens lose free access to the UK labour market. This is one of the reasons why our proposal indicated that participation in the EU budget would be vital for countries in the outer circle.

As far as the UK is concerned, it would be perfectly legitimate that it made a special budgetary contribution earmarked for low-income EU countries as a compensation for their reduced emigration possibilities and the entailed loss in economic wellbeing. Such a contribution could sway the Visegrad Four (the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia), whose governments have recently declared their opposition to allowing the UK access to the single market without free labour mobility. In addition, these and other EU countries from Central and Eastern Europe would probably wish to maintain close ties with the UK on security grounds.

3. Could the UK engage in regulatory and social dumping?

Some critics feared that the UK and other countries belonging to the outer circle of the CP would gain free access to the EU market for goods, services and capital without being bound by EU regulation. Could they therefore undertake regulatory competition? Again this is a misunderstanding of our proposal. All countries in the CP, whether they are inside or outside the EU, would have to abide by all existing EU single market regulation. We also discussed the need to enforce regulation throughout the entire area in a homogenous way.

All countries in the CP, whether they are inside or outside the EU, would have to abide by all existing EU single market regulation.

We would argue that for the EU it is actually beneficial that the UK remains inside the EU’s regulatory framework. If that was not the case, the possibilities for “dumping” policies may actually be larger, which could come at the expense of some EU countries. Regulatory competition could, however, take place in areas where there is no EU regulation (as is already the case for all EU countries).

This raises questions about the possibility of future EU regulation in areas that are not currently subject to EU rules, or future regulation that is stricter than current regulation. How would the UK would react to such a possibility as a CP member? In keeping with the spirit of our CP proposal, we would envisage that upon leaving the EU the UK remains in the integrated market, except as far as the free movement of workers is concerned. This means that it would retain all EU single market legislation. Over time, as the EU and the euro area deepen and additional single market legislation is introduced, the UK would have to make a decision. Does it want to retain its CP status and apply all EU legislation, or does it want a looser relationship with the EU? If it decided to depart, the UK would lose all its privileged access to the EU single market.

4. Does the Continental Partnership offer a viable governance structure?

Other criticisms of our proposal worried about its governance. We admit that our envisaged CP council, where the UK and other non-EU CP members would be consulted on EU legislation, creates a new layer in the EU legislative process, which is already cumbersome.  We are open to other forms of organisation but would insist that some form of a relatively close consultation is necessary among CP countries. However, this right to consultation should never mean having voting rights in the EU legislative process.

5. Do we believe that Brexit will really happen?

A final criticism is that we do not seem to believe that this divorce is actually happening. On the contrary, we take Brexit as a given. But we argue for a soft rather than a hard Brexit, for partnership rather than mutual ignorance.  The immediate reaction when a partner tells you that he or she wants to leave is usually denial and anger. With time, the focus normally shift to finding an arrangement that limits the damage for the children. After Brexit as well, the focus should be on establishing a framework to manage mutual interests between the EU and the UK, and possibly other non-EU countries in Europe.

We take Brexit as a given. But we argue for a soft rather than a hard Brexit, for partnership rather than mutual ignorance.

We believe that our CP proposal provides such a framework. The UK would need to continue to pay into the EU budget and it would need to accept all EU laws concerning the economy without having a vote on them. Both are necessary. Without contributing to the budget, no access to the single market can be granted and without a fair application of all laws, an integrated market cannot function. Reduced political influence is the price to be paid for being outside of the core club. In our view, it makes more sense to define the price in this sense than through an approach to economic access that would hurt the economy on both sides.

Finally, our proposal should not be read as meaning that we rejoice at Brexit or at limiting the free movement of workers. It is the British voters who have made this choice. They have effectively called for a new relationship between the UK and the EU, though they were not asked whether they wanted a soft or hard Brexit. This is the choice that the UK Government and its EU partners are now facing.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

View comments
Read article More by this author

Blog Post

The impact of Brexit on the Irish energy system – pragmatism vs. principles

Brexit promises pain for Ireland that could be cut off from the EU internal market and be left exposed to market instability in the UK. Georg Zachmann assesses the scale of the possible damage for Ireland, and how the UK and EU might use the special energy relations on the Irish island to commit to a pragmatic solution.

By: Georg Zachmann Topic: Energy & Climate, European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: November 21, 2017
Read about event More on this topic

Upcoming Event

Dec
12
12:30

The impact of Brexit for Research & Innovation in Europe

This event will feature a new and interactive format, with a restricted and high-level on-site audience and in parallel, it will be livestreamed on our website to remain public and attract the widest participation

Speakers: Alastair Buchan, Matt Dann, David Earnshaw, Kurt Deketelaere, Maryline Fiaschi, Martin Muller, Christian Naczinsky and Reinhilde Veugelers Topic: Innovation & Competition Policy Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels
Read article Download PDF

Policy Contribution

A ‘twin peaks’ vision for Europe

The organisation of the European Supervisory Authorities (ESAs) is based on a sectoral approach with one ESA for each sector, with separate authorities for banking, insurance and securities and markets. But is this sectoral approach still valid? This Policy Contribution outlines a long-term vision for the supervisory architecture in the European Union.

By: Dirk Schoenmaker and Nicolas Véron Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance, Finance & Financial Regulation Date: November 13, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The Bank of England’s dovish hike

For the first time since 2007, the Bank of England raised interest rates, with a hike of 25 basis points. At the same time, it provided forward guidance that outlines a very gradual path for future increases. We review the economic blogosphere’s reaction to this decision.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: November 6, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Falling Pound might not bring UK trade balance boost

The Pound Sterling depreciated by 14% against a basket of world currencies in the four months after the referendum vote to leave the EU. A number of pundits claimed that this would improve the UK trade balance and boost the economy. But the data do not show any visible improvement in the trade balance to date. Could it be that currency depreciations have less impact on trade balances than before?

By: Nicholas Branigan Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: October 31, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

EU borders: walking backwards from Northern Ireland to Cyprus

The Good Friday agreement put to rest age-old conflicts on Ireland. It also offered hope that the reunification of Cyprus might be possible within the European Union. Lately, however, the “Green Line” that divides the easternmost island of the EU, is viewed as a template for a soft border at the westernmost island of the Union after Brexit.

By: Stavros Zenios Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: October 25, 2017
Read article

Blog Post

India’s trade ties with the UK and EU

As EU and Indian leaders meet in Delhi, we look at the figures on trade. The UK’s place in the relationship warrants special attention. EU-India trade has more than tripled since 2000, but UK-India trade is largely static. The shift is especially noticeable for EU exports to India, where the UK share has dropped from 29% to 10%.

By: Maria Demertzis and Alexander Roth Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance, Global Economics & Governance Date: October 6, 2017
Read article More on this topic

Blog Post

Can roaming be saved after Brexit?

The referendum where UK voters chose to exit the European Union has many unanticipated consequences. One that is gaining visibility in the UK just now is the impact of Brexit on mobile roaming arrangements. How might the UK maintain roaming arrangements with the EU in the event of a hard Brexit?

By: J. Scott Marcus and Robert G. Clarke Topic: Innovation & Competition Policy Date: September 21, 2017
Read article Download PDF More by this author

Policy Contribution

Dutch Senate

Europe’s fourfold union: Updating the 2012 vision

The depiction of the euro area/European Union (EU) as a ‘fourfold union’ emerged in the first half of 2012 at the height of the euro-area crisis. In the past half-decade, Europe’s financial union has been significantly strengthened but remains incomplete and is challenged by Brexit. No consensus has been found on fiscal union and economic union has not made material progress, but political union might have advanced further than many observers realize.

By: Nicolas Véron Topic: Dutch Senate, European Macroeconomics & Governance, Finance & Financial Regulation, Testimonies Date: September 21, 2017
Read article Download PDF More on this topic

External Publication

Review of EU-third country cooperation on policies falling within the ITRE domain in relation to Brexit

What is the possible future relationship between the EU and the UK in light of Brexit? The report provides a critical assessment of the implications of existing models of cooperation between third countries and the European Union on energy, electronic communications, research policy and small business policy.

By: J. Scott Marcus, Georgios Petropoulos, André Sapir, Simone Tagliapietra, Alessio Terzi, Reinhilde Veugelers and Georg Zachmann Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: July 5, 2017
Read article More on this topic

Blog Post

Can EU actors keep using common law after Brexit?

English common law is the choice of law for financial contracts, even for parties in EU members with civil law systems. This creates a lucrative legal sector in the UK, but Brexit could make UK court decisions difficult to enforce in the EU. Parties will be able to continue using English common law after Brexit, but how will these contracts be enforced? Some continental courts are preparing to make judicial decisions on common law cases in the English language.

By: Uuriintuya Batsaikhan and Dirk Schoenmaker Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: June 22, 2017
Read article More by this author

Parliamentary Testimony

House of Commons

Exiting the European Union Committee

On 19 April 2017 Zsolt Darvas appeared as a witness at the Exiting the European Union Committee, the House of Commons, United Kingdom.

By: Zsolt Darvas Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance, House of Commons, Testimonies Date: June 20, 2017
Load more posts