Blog Post

Brexit, the pound and the UK current account

What’s at stake: UK PM Theresa May announced the intention to trigger article 50 by March 2017, the Pound Sterling crashed, and a dispute among Tesco and Unilever has resulted in Marmite shortage. Brexit means Brexit, and it continues to be highly discussed. It would be impossible to summarise all the economic blogosphere on Brexit. Our aim is to periodically update our readers on selected important aspects of what promises to be a long-lived topic of discussion. This time we are looking at economists’ view on the Pound crash and the UK current account.

By: Date: October 17, 2016 Topic: Uncategorized

First, let’s start from an update on the expected cost. A paper by the UK Treasury that was leaked this week suggests that a hard Brexit may cost £66 billion a year. The Treasury estimates that UK GDP would be between 5.4% and 9.5% of GDP lower after 15 years if the UK left the EU with no successor arrangement, with a central estimate of 7.5%. The net impact on public sector receipts – assuming no contributions to the EU and current receipts from the EU are replicated in full – would be a loss of between £38bn and £66bn per year after 15 years, driven by the smaller size of the economy. The draft cabinet committee paper is based on forecasts from a study into the predicted impact of quitting the EU published by George Osborne in April during the referendum campaign, and that has been controversial. The FT meanwhile has estimated that the UK would need to pay a fee of as much as €20 billion to leave the EU. More than €300bn of shared payment liabilities will need to be settled in the divorce reckoning, according to EU accounts. The €20bn upper estimate covers Britain’s share of continuing multi-year liabilities, including unpaid budget appropriations of €241 billion, pensions liabilities of €63.8 billion and future contractual and other spending commitments totalling about €32 billion.

Coming to the currency, Ashoka Mody argues that contrary to the dominant narrative, the pound’s depreciation carries a cheery message. The composite picture from financial markets tells the following story: Britain within the European Union became a magnet for speculative international financial capital; from its unrivalled role as financial gateway to Europe, arose a property-buying frenzy in London and neighbouring districts; silently but damagingly, the finance-property bubble also bid up the value of the pound, causing the pound to become overvalued for all other sectors of the British economy. Britain, quite literally, was living on borrowed time: British producers lost competitiveness at home and abroad and the sense that the British public was richer because the pound was stronger was an illusion. Mody argues that Brexit has fortuitously corrected this long-standing distortion in the British economy. The depreciation of the pound has corrected an overvaluation of the pound, improving the prospects of domestic producers. Rather than imposing a long-term cost, Brexit may, through a more reasonably priced pound, help expand British trade and productivity.

Paul Krugman has some notes on Brexit and how we should think about the drop in the Pound. Krugman argues that we should look at this is in terms of “home market effect” for trade in financial services. Financial services are subject to both internal and external economies of scale, which tends to concentrate them in a handful of huge financial centers around the world, one of which is the City of London. But now we face the prospect of seriously increased transaction costs between Britain and the rest of Europe, which creates an incentive to move those services away from the smaller economy (Britain) and into the larger (Europe). The smaller economy (Britain) can try to prevent this by paying lower wages and therefore make up in competitiveness what it lacks in market access. In effect, Britain would need a weaker currency to offset this adverse impact of its smaller market. Krugman argues that pre-Brexit, Britain was experiencing a version of the so-called Dutch disease. In its traditional form, this referred to the way natural resource exports crowd out manufacturing by keeping the currency strong. In the UK case, the City’s financial exports play the same role. So their weakening helps British manufacturing – and, maybe, the incomes of people who live far from the City and still depend directly or indirectly on manufacturing for their incomes. The policy moral is that  a weaker pound shouldn’t be viewed as an additional cost from Brexit, it’s just part of the adjustment. And it would be a big mistake to prop up the pound: old notions of an equilibrium exchange rate no longer apply.

UBS’ Global Co-Head of FX & Rates Strategy Themos Fiotakis writes on FT Alphaville that this is more more than a flash crash in sterling. Undoubtedly, uncertainties related to Brexit are a key driver of sterling weakness. Yet the fact that the pound has so far borne so much of the burden of those uncertainties is neither a coincidence nor a political miscalculation by market participants: it is a sign of underlying afflictions pre-dating the UK’s vote to leave.

From a currency perspective, the UK has entered this period of uncertainty from a disadvantageous starting point. The outsized UK current account deficit (currently at around 6% of GDP) suggests that the country is currently living well beyond its means because, in economic terms, very high current account deficits equate to deeply negative rates of aggregate savings. That the story told by this external deficit is largely benign between 2008 and early 2013 – when the UK’s economic recovery outpaced that of the rest of the world – but it turned sour between late 2013 and 2015, when income from the overseas earnings of UK-domiciled companies and the foreign investments of UK residents declined. This deterioration meant that the level of spending in the UK was no longer easy to finance from income generated abroad. Normally, this would have led to an economic deceleration and a gradual decline in sterling – which would ultimately have led the UK’s flow of funds back to balance. But this did not happen and over the past three years, the economy has extended its run on borrowed funds – funds which flew into the UK in the form of foreign direct investment on an unprecedented scale and were channelled in high proportion into real estate and infrastructure investments. Brexit or not, Fiotakis  argues, these inflows would eventually moderate, as the supply of new real estate and infrastructure picks up and price growth eases. But the uncertainties relating to the UK’s post-Brexit status obviously make this inflow of capital even less sustainable.

Writing on Bank Underground –  the Bank of England staff’s blog – Lauren Bowers also looks at the UK current account, and its financing. Since the financial crisis the UK’s fiscal and current account balances have persistently been in deficit. These ‘twin’ deficits are significant in historical terms, with a record peacetime fiscal deficit in 2009 and a record current account deficit in 2015. But how closely related are these ‘twins’ and do they pose a risk to financial stability?

Using a new ‘from-whom-to-whom’ dataset of sectoral balances, Bowers finds that the two deficits are not directly related to each other and argues that are being financed through relatively stable channels. The picture is one in which the financial sector has been increasingly financing the fiscal deficit through purchases of gilts, and foreign investment in private non-financial corporations has been driving the increased current account deficit. A proportion of FDI inflows and other private sector funds have being recycled through the financial system and in turn used to finance the fiscal deficit. So there is a link between the two deficits but Bowers do not think it should be worrying, for two reasons. First, the fiscal deficit has been increasingly financed by the domestic financial sector and domestic holdings may be more stable than foreign holdings where exchange rate risk is a concern. Second, with respect to the current account, the worsening of the IIP post-crisis has primarily been driven by inward FDI, and these are investments with a controlling interest and therefore often associated with stable and long-lasting financing relationships, as well as being less vulnerable to refinancing risk. While the recent EU referendum result may influence new FDI inflows, Bowers argues that the reversal of existing investments is still unlikely relative to other types of financing, so this trend does not appear to pose significant risks.

Grep Ip on the Wall Street Journal writes that the plunge in the pound sterling and an uptick in British government yields are a completely logical adjustment to the changed environment in which Britain will soon find itself. For British companies’ products to remain competitive, they will either have to cut their prices or find buyers in other markets that transportation and trade barriers had previously made unappealing. In either case, more costs will be incurred producing the same exports, which undermines already lackluster productivity. Lower sterling compensates by reducing British costs relative to other countries.

Because what Britons sell will be less competitive, their standard of living must also drop relative to the rest of the world. Lower sterling does that too. As import prices rise, so will inflation, cutting into real wages. British consumption will shift towards domestic from foreign products. However, Britain is already near full employment and does not have the productive capacity to both make more exports and replace imports. The Bank of England cannot keep rates low forever in the face of productive constraints and higher inflation. Eventually, higher interest rates must tamp down domestic consumption and smooth the way for the reorientation of productive capacity. Britain has the developed world’s largest current-account deficit. Financing that deficit relies on the world’s willingness to buy British stocks and bonds, which in turn depends on their confidence that British profits and incomes can service those obligations. Brexit impairs that, so Britain cannot rely so much on the kindness of strangers to finance its consumption. Ip argues that lower sterling helps in several ways. By boosting exports and dampening imports, it will help narrow the trade component of the current-account deficit. By increasing the value of British investments abroad, it improves the investment-income deficit. And by reassuring foreign investors that future appreciation is more likely, a cheap pound eases the financing of the deficit.

While the former BoE governor Mervyn King is reported to have said that the fall in Sterling is a “welcome change” that has generated “reactions which are over the top”, Simon Wren-Lewis of Mainly Macro  is asking himself a very unusual question: did the Bank of England (BoE), by any chance, cause Brexit?

The question is grounded on the hypothesis that the BoE might have missed an important change in the labour market structure. The reasoning goes as follows. Suppose that by the mid-2000s, immigration from the EU (and the potential for additional immigration) had led to an important shift in the UK labour market, so that the natural rate of unemployment (NAIRU) has fallen. While this is a thought-exercise, Wren-Lewis cites a  report by Paul Gregg and Steve Machin, providing some evidence of a structural shift in the UK labour market in the mid-2000s. The meaning of this is that unemployment could be lower without leading to wage increases that threaten the inflation target, because workers fear that the employer can resort to finding much cheaper overseas labour.

Ideally, the Bank should realise that there has been a change because wages will start falling faster than they would expect based on previous relationships. However that effect may be masked by the well documented employee and employer reluctance to actually cut nominal wages. Add in the shock of the financial crisis, and this change in the way the labour market works might well be missed. How does all this link to Brexit? Wren-Lewis argues that if the change did occur, and if the Bank of England had acknowledged the structural change in the labor market, then monetary policy would be much more expansionary, bringing unemployment well below the 5% mark. Nominal wage growth would have been stronger, and a buoyant labour market would have generated a feel good factor among workers. With more vacancies and less unemployment, concerns about immigration would have begun to fade. The Brexit vote would still have been close, but would have gone the other way.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

View comments
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

President Trump’s budget: the 3% growth quandary

What’s at stake: the Trump administration released its full budget proposal. Economists have been arguing about the feasibility of the underlying growth assumptions, and on whether there is a double-counting implied. We review the most recent contributions to this debate.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: May 29, 2017
Read about event More on this topic

Upcoming Event

Jun
2
12:30

Substance requirements for financial firms moving out from the UK

In the run-up to Brexit, UK-based financial firms are considering how to organize their operations across the future divide between the UK and EU27. This event will discuss the regulatory requirements on how self-sustaining the operations in the EU should be, and implications for the single market and third countries.

Speakers: Gerry Cross, Simon Gleeson and Nicolas Véron Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation Location: Bruegel, Rue de la Charité 33, 1210 Brussels
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Pia Hüttl

Dial N for NAIRU, or not?

What’s at stake: The concept of the NAIRU (Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment) has recently divided the minds in the economic blogosphere. We review the most important contributions on its usefulness, its shortcomings, alternatives and we discuss why it is such a contested concept.

By: Pia Hüttl Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: May 22, 2017
Read article More on this topic

Blog Post

Uuriintuya Batsaikhan
DSC_0794

UK economic performance post-Brexit

What’s at stake: Almost a year after the UK voted to leave the European Union, its economic performance has showed mixed results. The risks of a Brexit-induced recession do not seem to be materialising. On the contrary, up until the end of 2016 the UK saw a continuation of strong consumer spending and strong output in consumer-focused activities. However, the UK economy is showing signs of slowing down in the first quarter of 2017, with weak growth in the services sector and business investments. In addition, strong consumption growth started to cool down as individuals’ purchasing power declines due to a weaker exchange rate. This leads to a question whether it is the beginning of the Brexit slowdown. We review the contributions made on this topic in the last year.

By: Uuriintuya Batsaikhan and Justine Feliu Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: May 15, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

André Sapir

International arbitration is the way to settle the UK’s Brexit bill

The UK-EU financial settlement risks becoming a toxic stumbling block in Brexit negotiations. But there are actually much more important issues to discuss. To diffuse the issue, both sides should agree to independent international arbitration.

By: André Sapir Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: May 11, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Opinion

Guntram B. Wolff

Brexit will change millions of lives. Our leaders must do more than posture

From the land border with Ireland to expats’ pension rights, there is much to negotiate.

By: Guntram B. Wolff Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: May 8, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

The US and the productivity puzzle

What’s at stake: Productivity growth fell sharply following the global financial crisis and has remained sluggish since, inducing many to talk of a “productivity puzzle”. In the US, we may be seeing what look like early signs of a reversal. We review recent contributions on this theme.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: May 8, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Podcast

Podcast

How will Europe's banking system respond to future challenges?

After the financial crisis, the EU has taken measures to create conditions for a safer banking sector. One of the key measures to do that is the creation of the banking union. How successful has the implementation of the new framework been so far? How will issues in the Italian banking sector be addressed? And how will Brexit change the European banking sector?

By: The Sound of Economics Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation Date: May 5, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

The Trump tax cut

What’s at stake: on Wednesday, the Trump administration - now 100 days old - unveiled a draft tax plan including the intention to enact a radical cut to the corporate income tax, lowering it to 15 percent. While we are still missing details on how this and other measures would be implemented, we review some of the early reactions.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: May 2, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Silvia Merler

The decline of the labour share of income

What’s at stake: at odds with the conventional wisdom of constant factor shares, the portion of national income accruing to labour has been trending downward in the last three decades. This phenomenon has been linked to globalisation as well as to the change in the technological landscape - particularly “robotisation”. We review the recent literature on this issue.

By: Silvia Merler Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: April 24, 2017
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Uuriintuya Batsaikhan

Embracing the silver economy

What’s at stake: The oldest human in known history was a Frenchwoman called Jeanne Calment who celebrated her 122nd birthday in 1997. Thanks to advances in technology and medicine humans living until 100, if not 122, might not be an exception in the near future. Ageing, while described as a looming demographic crisis, also offers a silver lining. Business in rapidly ageing societies is already adapting their strategies to navigate the “silver economy”. This blogs review looks at the implications of the silver economy on growth, productivity and innovation as well as the opportunities offered by the silver industry.

By: Uuriintuya Batsaikhan Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: April 10, 2017
Read article More by this author

Blog Post

OLYMPUS DIGITAL CAMERA

Is China’s innovation strategy a threat?

What’s at stake: A number of recent contributions accuse China of acquiring technology from abroad without respecting international rules. This blog reviews the current debate that focuses on China’s supposed push to modernise its industry and the challenges for advanced economies. By leapfrogging to high-tech manufacturing products, the strategy threatens the competitive advantage of the US and the EU. The international rules-based order is put to a test facing large-scale government support to high-value added sectors and anti-competitive behaviour.

By: Robert Kalcik Topic: Global Economics & Governance, Innovation & Competition Policy Date: April 3, 2017
Load more posts