Blog Post

Microfoundations in Macroeconomics

What’s at stake:The role of aggregate or ad-hoc models for policy discussions in an age where journal papers in macro theory are always microfounded DSGE was brought to the forefront more than 2 years ago by Paul Krugman’s provocative essay `How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?’ (seehere for a review). Since then, an interesting discussion – in the sense that it is not a discussion between those who do not understand the language of modern macroeconomics and those who do – has been going in the blogosphere on the importance of microfoundations for macroeconomic analysis. In a previouspost,we outlined recent extensions of the basic IS-LM framework and pointed to a specific strand (modeling financial frictions into New Keynesian models) of a burgeoning literature: models with heterogeneous agents. We use the flurry of debate this week on the blogosphere to provide more background on these heterogeneous agents models and on other alternative approaches to the representative agent framework (behavioral macro models and agent based models).

By: Date: March 9, 2012 Topic: Innovation & Competition Policy

What’s at stake: The role of aggregate or ad-hoc models for policy discussions in an age where journal papers in macro theory are always microfounded DSGE was brought to the forefront more than 2 years ago by Paul Krugman’s provocative essay `How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?’ (see here for a review). Since then, an interesting discussion – in the sense that it is not a discussion between those who do not understand the language of modern macroeconomics and those who do – has been going in the blogosphere on the importance of microfoundations for macroeconomic analysis. In a previous post, we outlined recent extensions of the basic IS-LM framework and pointed to a specific strand (modeling financial frictions into New Keynesian models) of a burgeoning literature: models with heterogeneous agents. We use the flurry of debate this week on the blogosphere to provide more background on these heterogeneous agents models and on other alternative approaches to the representative agent framework (behavioral macro models and agent based models).

Microfounded and some other useful aggregate models

Mark Thoma points out that the reason that many of us looked backward for a model to help us understand the present crisis is that none of the current models were capable of explaining what we were going through. The New Keynesians model was built to capture "ordinary" business cycles driven by price sluggishness of the sort that can be captured by the Calvo model of price rigidity. But the standard versions of this model do not explain how financial collapse of the type we just witnessed come about, hence they have little to say about what to do about them.

Simon Wren-Lewis argues that some aggregate models contain critical features that can be derived from a number of different microfoundations. In that situation, it is natural to want to work with these aggregate models. We could even say that they are more useful, because they have a generality that would be missing if we focused on one particular microfoundation. Suppose there is not just one, but perhaps a variety of particular worlds which would lead to this set of aggregate macro relationships. Furthermore, suppose that more than one of these particular worlds was a reasonable representation of reality. In these circumstances, it would seem sensible to go straight to the aggregate model, and ignore microfoundations

In a follow-up post Simon Wren-Lewis argues that the microfoundations purist view is a mistake because it confuses ‘currently has no clear microfoundations’ with ‘cannot ever be microfounded’. Developing new microfounded macro models is hard. It is hard because these models need to be internally consistent. If we think that, say, consumption in the real world shows more inertia than in the baseline intertemporal model, we cannot just add some lags into the aggregate consumption function. Instead we need to think about what microeconomic phenomena might generate that inertia. We need to rework all relevant optimization problems adding in this new ingredient. Many other aggregate relationships besides the consumption function could change as a result. When we do this, we might find that although our new idea does the trick for consumption, it leads to implausible behavior elsewhere, and so we need to go back to the drawing board. It is very important to do all this, but it takes time. So using aggregate (or useful, or ad hoc) models should be respected if there is empirical evidence supporting the ad hoc aggregate relationship, and if the implications of that relationship could be important. In these circumstances, it would be a mistake for academic analysis to have to wait for the microfoundations work to be done.

The Lucas Critique and the Representative Agent framework

Noahpinion points that the Phillips Curve is the famous example of why aggregate relationships might not be useful without understanding the microfoundations. That doesn’t make aggregate-only models useless, but it should make people cautious about using them. The usual answer is that "microfoundations make models immune to the Lucas Critique." The idea is that the rules of individual behavior don’t change when policy changes, so basing our models purely on the rules of individual behavior will allow us to predict the effects of government policies. Actually, it’s not clear this really works. For example, most microfounded models rely on utility functions with constant parameters – these are the "tastes" that Bob Lucas and other founders of modern macro believed to be fundamental and unchanging. But I’d be willing to bet that different macro policies can change people’s risk aversion. If that’s the case, then using microfoundations doesn’t really answer the Lucas Critique.

The use of representative agents in macroeconomics has something to do with the recent soul searching among macroeconomists and the critique against the profession.

In a review of Michael Woodford’s major and very influential monetary theory textbook (Interest and Prices), Kevin Hoover argued that if Keynesians were stigmatized for dealing only in aggregates, the representative-agent is nothing else but an aggregate in microeconomic drag. He recalls that most important – but widely neglected – results of general equilibrium theory in the 1950s and 1960s shown that the representative-agent’s utility function cannot be thought of as ranking the outcomes of policy in a manner that deeply reflects those of individual agents.

AlphaSources provides some useful background about the origins of the Representative Agent. It first appeared in the context of Alfred Marshall’s Principles of Economics in the form of the representative firm and Marshall originally conjured this entity in the context of constructing a supply curve for the industry. After a devastating critique by, among others, John Maynard Keynes and Lionel Robbins the idea of the representative agent was put to rest in the first part of the 20th century. According to Hartley (1996) the first use of representative agents in a post Marshall perspective has its origins in the period in which neo-classical economics was reaching its zenith. Concretely, Lucas and Rapping (1970) is cited as the first contribution using a representative agent detailing the theory of intertemporal labor supply which is a core assumption of most real business cycle models (see D. Romer, 2006, ch. 4).

Microfoundations or "Microfoundations"

Paul Krugman argues that when making comparisons between economics and physical science we should keep in mind that what we call “microfoundations” are not like physical laws. Heck, they’re not even true. Maximizing consumers are just a metaphor, possibly useful in making sense of behavior, but possibly not. The metaphors we use for microfoundations have no claim to be regarded as representing a higher order of truth than the ad hoc aggregate metaphors we use in IS-LM or whatever. Noahpinion argues that macroeconomists to have basically done one of two things: either A) gone right on using aggregate models, while writing down some "microfoundations" to please journal editors, or B) drawn policy recommendations directly from incorrect models of individual behavior.

Kevin Grier, professor at the University of Oklahoma, points that we don’t even have very good micro foundations for money! We just put it in the utility function or arbitrarily assume a "cash in advance" constraint. Amazingly though, Central Banks in the Western world have spent a lot of money and economist-hours trying to construct DSGE models that are actually useful for forecasting. This effort has largely led to the de facto abandonment of micro-foundations. In the quest to make the models "work" we often either choose whatever micro-foundation that gives the best forecast regardless of micro evidence about whether or not it is accurate, or we just add ad hoc, non-micro-founded "frictions" to create more inertia. Or we just add more and more "shocks" to the model and say things like, "much of the variation in X is caused by shocks to the markup".

Robert Waldmann points that there is a tension between the two pillars of Modern Macroeconomic Methodology: Milton Friedman’s methodology of positive economics and the Lucas critique. A nickel version of Friedman’s methodology of positive economics start with models can be useful even if they are not true (even if they are false by definition). This is universally agreed. This implies that we shouldn’t treat models as hypotheses to be tested, so we are not necessarily interested in every testable implication of the model. Instead we should care about the implications of the model for the variables, which matter to us.

Beyond the RA framework: Models with heterogeneous agents

Douglas Clement reviews for the Minneapolis Fed a flourishing literature where researchers explore the promise of economic models that allow for human variation. Including different tastes or characteristics in models have led to a reformulation of many previous results derived with simple representative agents. While standard models tend to find small impact of recessions, heterogeneous agents highlight distributive effects and thus point out much larger overall effects on unemployment and wealth. The consequences of inflation have also be revised: expected inflation has a negative impact on the poor because they hold more of their wealth in cash than do the rich, but, on the other hand, it creates large losses for older, wealthy households because they hold more bonds than others. Deflation could have the opposite consequences. 

Simon Wren-Lewis points to a couple interesting questions raised by the role of microfoundations in macroeconomics: Can the microfoundations approach embrace all kinds of heterogeneity, or will such models lose their attractiveness in their complexity? Does sticking with simple, representative agent macro impart some kind of bias? Does a microfoundations approach discourage investigation of the more ‘difficult’ but more important issues? Might both these questions suggest a link between too simple a micro based view and a failure to understand what was going on before the financial crash? Are alternatives to microfoundations modeling methodologically coherent? Is empirical evidence ever going to be strong and clear enough to trump internal consistency?

Jonathan Heathcote, Kjetil Storesletten and Gianluca Violante have, for example, applied these heterogeneous models to investigate the impact of rising wages inequality on labor supply and consumption. Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez and Stefanie Stantcheva have also Included heterogeneous agents in normative models of taxation leading to a reconsideration of important results in that field.

Beyond the RA framework: The agent based approach to macroeconomics

Doyne Farmer at Santa Fe has become one of the leading proponents of the agent based model approach to macroeconomics. An agent-based model is a computerized simulation of a number of decision-makers (agents) and institutions, which interact through prescribed rules. Contrary to standard dynamic economic models, these models do not rely on the assumption that the economy will move towards a predetermined equilibrium state and they do not assume an a priori form of rationality. Behaviors are modeled according to what is observed: researchers thus need a tremendous amount of data in order to identify robust patterns. The models allow for non-equilibrium states and non-linearities:  thus they can generate easily non-market clearing phenomena and endogenous crisis.

In an article in Nature in 2009, Farmer and Foley claimed that these models could include financial interactions in a much more complex and realistic way than usual models. Farmer and his team are now developing an agent-based model of the housing market to mimic the current financial crisis. The team collects data on actual people to calibrate a rich model with millions of interacting agents. This is what they call a bottom-up approach to macroeconomics: see here from a more detailed presentation of that approach by INET.

In order to convince most economists, agent based models need to show that the mechanisms modeled in the complex interactions are nevertheless still clear and intuitive and all but a new black box. Richard Serlin points, in particular, that aggregation is a huge challenge for microfounded models, since complex systems often have chaotic properties.

Beyond the RA framework: IKE and Behavioral Macro

Kevin Hoover has recently written what he calls "an Econ 1 (Principles) version of the Imperfect Knowledge Economics" (IKE) developed by Roman Frydman and Michael D. Goldberg which aims to provide an alternative to the representative agent utility. The IKE sees investors as adopting various strategies for forming expectations of future prices. These strategies are not unique, so that there is a distribution of strategies and investors may alter their strategies from time to time. Roman Frydman and Michael D. Goldberg have especially applied their new approach to asset pricing and financial markets. They complain that current models are only “economics of magical thinking”. Behavioral economics has shown that market participants do not act like conventional economists would predict “rational individuals” to act. But according to Frydman and Goldberg it would be also wrong to interpret these empirical findings to mean that many market participants are irrational, prone to emotion, or ignore economic fundamentals for other reasons. People can be rational in different ways depending on the context and information available to them.

Roger Guesnerie has a rather similar view: developing new approaches to rationality and expectations is the promising way that economics should follow in order to build macroeconomics models in the post crisis era.

Paul De Grauwe recently wrote a textbook on Behavioral Macroeconomics. Contrary to mainstream top-down models in which agents are capable of understanding the whole picture and use this superior information to determine their optimal plans, the models used in this book are bottom-up models in which all agents experience cognitive limitations. As a result, these agents are only capable of understanding and using small bits of information. Agents use simple rules of behavior. These models are not devoid of rationality. Agents in these models behave rationally in that they are willing to learn from their mistakes. Importantly, these models produce a radically different macroeconomic dynamics than RA models.


Republishing and referencing

Bruegel considers itself a public good and takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference, clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.

View comments
Read article More by this author

Blog Post

It’s hard to live in the city: Berlin’s rent freeze and the economics of rent control

A proposal in Berlin to ban increases in rent for the next five years sparked intense debate in Germany. Similar policies to the Mietendeckel are currently being discussed in London and NYC. All three proposals reflect and raise similar concerns – the increase in per-capita incomes is not keeping pace with increases in rents, but will a cap do more harm than good? We review recent views on the matter.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: July 8, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The breakdown of the covered interest rate parity condition

A textbook condition of international finance breaks down. Economic research identifies the interplay between divergent monetary policies and new financial regulation as the source of the puzzle, and generates concerns about unintended consequences for financing conditions and financial stability.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: Finance & Financial Regulation Date: July 1, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The June Eurogroup meeting: Reflections on BICC

The Eurogroup met on June 13th to discuss the deepening of the economic and monetary union (EMU) and prepare the discussions for the Euro Summit. From the meeting came two main deliverables: an agreement over a budgetary instrument for competitiveness and convergence and the reform of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) treaty texts. We review economists’ first impressions.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: June 24, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The campaign against ‘nonsense’ output gaps

A campaign against “nonsense” consensus output gaps has been launched on social media. It has triggered responses focusing on the implications of output gaps for fiscal policy under EU rules, especially for Italy. But the debate about the reliability of output-gap estimates is more wide-ranging.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: June 17, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The inverted yield curve

Longer-term yields falling below shorter-term yields have historically preceded recessions. Last week, the US 10-year yield was 21 basis points below the 3-month yield, a feat last seen during the summer of 2007. Is the current yield curve a trustworthy barometer for future growth?

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: June 11, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The 'seven' ceiling: China's yuan in trade talks

Investors and the public have been looking at the renminbi with caution after the Trump administration threatened to increase duties on countries that intervene in the markets to devalue/undervalue their currency relative to the dollar. The fear is that China could weaponise its currency following the further increase in tariffs imposed by the United States in early May. What is the likelihood of this happening and what would be the consequences for the existing tensions with the United States, as well as for the global economy?

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: June 3, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The next ECB president

On May 28th, EU heads of state and government will start the nomination process for the next ECB president. Leaving names of possible candidates aside, this review tries to isolate the arguments about what qualifications the new president should have and what challenges he or she is likely to face.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: May 27, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

The latest European growth-rate estimates

The quarterly growth rate of the euro area in Q1 2019 was 0.4% (1.5% annualized), considerably higher than the low growth rates of the previous two quarters. This blog reviews the reaction to the release of these numbers and the discussion they have triggered about the euro area’s economic challenges.

By: Konstantinos Efstathiou Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: May 20, 2019
Read article More by this author

Blog Post

Is an electric car a cleaner car?

An article published by the Ifo Institute in Germany compares the carbon footprint of a battery-electric car to that of a diesel car, and argues a higher share of electric cars will not contribute to reducing German carbon dioxide emissions. Respondents rejected the authors’ calculations as unrealistic and biased, and pointed to a series of studies that conclude the opposite. We summarise the article and responses to it.

By: Michael Baltensperger Topic: Energy & Climate, Innovation & Competition Policy Date: May 13, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

All eyes on the Fed

Last week the US Federal Reserve left the federal funds rate unchanged and lowered the interest rate on excess reserves. We review economists’ recent views on the monetary policy conduct and priorities of the United States’ central bank system.

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: Global Economics & Governance Date: May 6, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Is this blog post legal (under new EU copyright law)?

How new EU rules on using snippets from news publishers and on copyright infringement liability might affect circulation of information, revenue distribution, market power and EU business competitiveness.

By: Catarina Midoes Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: April 8, 2019
Read article More on this topic More by this author

Blog Post

Secular stagnation and the future of economic stabilisation

Larry Summers’ and Łukasz Rachel’s most recent study documents a secular fall in neutral real rates in advanced economies. According to the authors, this fall would be even more marked in the absence of offsetting fiscal policies. Policymaking in a world of permanently low interest rates may be hard to navigate, especially in troubled waters. We review economists’ views on the matter

By: Inês Goncalves Raposo Topic: European Macroeconomics & Governance Date: April 1, 2019
Load more posts